Vertical Boundaries of a firm
The vertical boundaries of the firm
illustrate which activities the firm would perform itself and which it would
leave to the market.
Vertical Boundaries of a Firm
The production of any good or service
usually requires a wide range of activities organized in a vertical chain. Production activities are said to flow from
upstream suppliers of raw inputs to downstream manufacturers, distributors and
retailers.
Activities in the chain include
processing and handling activities, which are associated directly with the
processing and distribution of inputs and outputs, and professional support
activities, such as accounting and planning.
Another set of questions that may arise when managers/firm operators
attempt to define their firm is to ask:
What activities do we do? What do
we leave to the market? This is known as
the “make-or-buy” problem.
Most Common Make-or-buy Fallacies
1. Buy to avoid
the costs of making. This argument
ignores the fact that the firm it buys from will have to incur these costs and
will charge accordingly. That is, whoever manufactures the product bears the
risk of fluctuating volumes; if it's costly for you, then it is probably costly
for others as well. Moreover, an outside firm may be able to have a greater
number of suppliers for its product or it may simply be more efficient than
your firm.
Example:
Intel licenses production to outside firms. Does this avoid cost? Only if the
outside firms offer some advantage. In this case, the outside firms can better
handle capacity due to scope economies.
2. Make to avoid
paying profits to others. It is useful
to consider where profits are coming from: 1) Profit may be the normal risk
adjusted return to the “maker.” That is, profits may represent the return
necessary to attract investments and would be required of the firm that makes
internally just as they are required of independent firms; or 2) Profit may
come from monopoly power. If a supplier charges $300,000 for a product that
costs $200,000 to produce, why doesn't someone else enter the market? Without
an answer to this question, you can't be so sure of the savings of making
yourself.
3. Assure
supply and avoid fluctuating prices during peak demand or short supply. If you start to manufacture, you actually
start to play the role of commodity speculator.
Reasons to Buy
1. A market
specialist sells to many buyers and can better take advantage of economies of
scale and scope than an in-house department could if it produced only for its
own needs. If there are economies of scale then, the make-or-buy decision can
be resolved by determining whether the firm or its independent suppliers are
better able to achieve them. Economies of scale are present whenever costs fall
as volume increases. These economies are usually associated with fixed
investments.
·
If Q > Minimum Efficient Scale
(MES), then make. This situation can be seen in Campbell's decision to backward
integrate into soup can production.
·
If Q < MES, then buy. Costs can be
decreased if there is additional production. Who is more likely to take on
added production, the firm or its partner? We generally observe that it is
easier and more likely for the independent partner to grow.
The
importance of economies of scale in defining the boundaries of the firm also
extend to individual activities (The division of labor is limited). Adam Smith
wrote about a pin factory in which some workers only made straight parts, some
made the crowns, and some put them together. This process made sense because 1)
Economies of Scale--routinization of two factors improved the productivity of
the specialists, and 2) Large Demand--there was enough demand for pins that
each worker could be kept busy doing just one task. Smith described this
division of labor as natural in any market as volume increases enough to
justify specialists.
2. Efficiency
and Incentives. Independent firms may have more incentive to innovate than a
division within a firm because departments can never be sure if they are making
/losing money. That is, the owner of an independent firm faces stern discipline
from the market and keeps every dollar he makes. Conversely, it is harder to
match pay to performance for individual managers of internal divisions.
Efficiency and incentive concerns include:
· Transfer pricing--it is hard to
determine the appropriate prices to charge internal divisions. For example, how
should we charge for IT in each division?
·
Equity concerns
· Influence costs--lobbying for
resources may lead to biased information and destructive competition within the
firm; internal divisions may lobby each other, raising the cost of production.
Using independent firms allows you to keep these issues distinct.
3. Culture.
Consolidation of independent firms can also create legendary culture clashes.
In
summary, the market is a powerful force for technical efficiency and
independence/autonomy is a powerful motivator. These forces must be weighed
against those that favor integration (outlined below).
Reasons to Make
1. Coordination
Costs. The steps in the vertical chain must fit together. Fit can be along any
number of dimensions:
·
Time: movies should be released to
theaters at same time as advertising
·
Size: O rings on space shuttle,
stamped parts for automobiles
·
Color: Bennetton's spring line-up
·
Sequence: Curriculum within a
university
Fit
can be attained through either doing tasks in-house or through contract. Contracts often stipulate bonuses for
performance exceeding expectations or penalties for failing to meet specified
criteria.
·
Highway construction on Chicago's Dan
Ryan Expressway: bonuses were given to construction firms to finish the job
early
·
Silicon chip production: tolerance
penalties assessed
Alternatives to Make-or-buy
There
are alternatives to either making or buying.
One such alternative is long-term contracting. This option eliminates
some flexibility that is especially important in declining economies (where you
may not know if the firm will be around in the long-term). Such flexibility is
not as critical in growing economies where all the players are expected to
continue to do well (Japanese Keiretsu).
The Value Chain
Michael
Porter introduced the concept of the value chain in 1985. His scheme takes the
vertical chain and puts dollar values to it. This helps to identify those steps
in the vertical chain where the most value is added. The value chain is
critical to the concept of positioning (how the firm chooses to create
value/differentiate itself for customers). The value chain is a tool that
portrays the firm as being made up of a set of value-creating activities. The
value of a good as it moves through the value chain is equal to the price it
can be sold for in the market. When the chain consists of independent firms,
these prices are easily identified. When the chain consists of consecutive
steps done within the same firm, these prices may or may not be identified.
These are called transfer prices--a price that tries to measure what a fair
market price would be for a good passed through an internal market. These prices
are often based on comparisons with similar goods sold in the outside market.
Porter's
chain has five primary activities:
Purchasing/inventory
handling
Production
Distribution
Sales/marketing
Customer
service
Three
support activities:
Human
resources management
Research
and development/design
Corporate
infrastructure
No comments:
Post a Comment